- This topic has 66 replies, 12 voices, and was last updated 17 years, 2 months ago by patientrenter.
-
AuthorPosts
-
August 20, 2007 at 12:32 PM #78535August 20, 2007 at 2:44 PM #78411daveljParticipant
patientrenter,
you posted: “I don’t think the difference between the prices today of conforming and nonconforming mortgages is driven by differences in risk. It’s just an indicator of the value of the government guarantee tacked onto the mortgage security when it’s packaged and sold. If you can remove the charge for loan default risk, then of course the price of the loan goes down. This is just as true at $942K as at $417K.”
I would have completely agreed with that assessment 6 months ago and it probably still holds true to some degree today. Here’s the issue, however, as I see it going forward: the rates that the GSAs will be charging for all of these loans will be increasing regardless of how they decide to define a “conforming mortgage.” From a big picture standpoint, what I’m trying to get at is that, ultimately, somebody’s gotta pay when mortgages default, regardless of whether it’s MBS investors or taxpayers via a GSA bailout. Consequently, while it may help a little bit at the margin – because as you correctly point out, the charge for loan defaults is reduced (or perhaps “more dispersed” is a better way of putting it) – it doesn’t really address the REAL problem, which is affordability. If the difference in being able to afford a mortgage is 50 bps (lets just assume that’s the long-term “GSA advantage” for the moment), then one shouldn’t take out the loan. The real problem, at the end of the day, is prices must come down. Raising the conforming limit is a small bandage, in my opinion. But I could be wrong.
August 20, 2007 at 2:44 PM #78537daveljParticipantpatientrenter,
you posted: “I don’t think the difference between the prices today of conforming and nonconforming mortgages is driven by differences in risk. It’s just an indicator of the value of the government guarantee tacked onto the mortgage security when it’s packaged and sold. If you can remove the charge for loan default risk, then of course the price of the loan goes down. This is just as true at $942K as at $417K.”
I would have completely agreed with that assessment 6 months ago and it probably still holds true to some degree today. Here’s the issue, however, as I see it going forward: the rates that the GSAs will be charging for all of these loans will be increasing regardless of how they decide to define a “conforming mortgage.” From a big picture standpoint, what I’m trying to get at is that, ultimately, somebody’s gotta pay when mortgages default, regardless of whether it’s MBS investors or taxpayers via a GSA bailout. Consequently, while it may help a little bit at the margin – because as you correctly point out, the charge for loan defaults is reduced (or perhaps “more dispersed” is a better way of putting it) – it doesn’t really address the REAL problem, which is affordability. If the difference in being able to afford a mortgage is 50 bps (lets just assume that’s the long-term “GSA advantage” for the moment), then one shouldn’t take out the loan. The real problem, at the end of the day, is prices must come down. Raising the conforming limit is a small bandage, in my opinion. But I could be wrong.
August 20, 2007 at 2:44 PM #78558daveljParticipantpatientrenter,
you posted: “I don’t think the difference between the prices today of conforming and nonconforming mortgages is driven by differences in risk. It’s just an indicator of the value of the government guarantee tacked onto the mortgage security when it’s packaged and sold. If you can remove the charge for loan default risk, then of course the price of the loan goes down. This is just as true at $942K as at $417K.”
I would have completely agreed with that assessment 6 months ago and it probably still holds true to some degree today. Here’s the issue, however, as I see it going forward: the rates that the GSAs will be charging for all of these loans will be increasing regardless of how they decide to define a “conforming mortgage.” From a big picture standpoint, what I’m trying to get at is that, ultimately, somebody’s gotta pay when mortgages default, regardless of whether it’s MBS investors or taxpayers via a GSA bailout. Consequently, while it may help a little bit at the margin – because as you correctly point out, the charge for loan defaults is reduced (or perhaps “more dispersed” is a better way of putting it) – it doesn’t really address the REAL problem, which is affordability. If the difference in being able to afford a mortgage is 50 bps (lets just assume that’s the long-term “GSA advantage” for the moment), then one shouldn’t take out the loan. The real problem, at the end of the day, is prices must come down. Raising the conforming limit is a small bandage, in my opinion. But I could be wrong.
August 20, 2007 at 9:04 PM #78548patientrenterParticipantI think we are mostly in agreement, davelj. I suppose I am a little more suspicious that the 50bp GSE ‘advantage’ can be boosted by govt action in two ways, thereby making conforming loans more valuable and the conforming limit more important. My half-century on this planet has probably just made me too cynical.
What are those 2 ways? The GSAs have to charge at least the long-term default rate on the loans so they can break even. Above that, they charge for risk.
GSA rate = risk-free rate + long-term default rate + risk charge.
The government can and does manage the risk charge down, by implicitly guaranteeing GSA bonds, and by allowing them to run on very low capital. They can manage it down further by allowing them to hold even less capital, or hinting more strongly that they’ll stand behind the GSAs in a crisis.
They can manage the charge for the long-term default rate down by saying that they’ll step in in a ‘crisis’ to subsidize the GSAs. Since most default costs over several economic cycles are incurred in the darkest depths of downturns, this effective reduction in the cost to the GSAs of the defaults could be dressed up as govt just doing what it should do – stepping in when all else fails.
I’m glad you are less cynical than me!
Patient renter in OC
August 20, 2007 at 9:04 PM #78676patientrenterParticipantI think we are mostly in agreement, davelj. I suppose I am a little more suspicious that the 50bp GSE ‘advantage’ can be boosted by govt action in two ways, thereby making conforming loans more valuable and the conforming limit more important. My half-century on this planet has probably just made me too cynical.
What are those 2 ways? The GSAs have to charge at least the long-term default rate on the loans so they can break even. Above that, they charge for risk.
GSA rate = risk-free rate + long-term default rate + risk charge.
The government can and does manage the risk charge down, by implicitly guaranteeing GSA bonds, and by allowing them to run on very low capital. They can manage it down further by allowing them to hold even less capital, or hinting more strongly that they’ll stand behind the GSAs in a crisis.
They can manage the charge for the long-term default rate down by saying that they’ll step in in a ‘crisis’ to subsidize the GSAs. Since most default costs over several economic cycles are incurred in the darkest depths of downturns, this effective reduction in the cost to the GSAs of the defaults could be dressed up as govt just doing what it should do – stepping in when all else fails.
I’m glad you are less cynical than me!
Patient renter in OC
August 20, 2007 at 9:04 PM #78698patientrenterParticipantI think we are mostly in agreement, davelj. I suppose I am a little more suspicious that the 50bp GSE ‘advantage’ can be boosted by govt action in two ways, thereby making conforming loans more valuable and the conforming limit more important. My half-century on this planet has probably just made me too cynical.
What are those 2 ways? The GSAs have to charge at least the long-term default rate on the loans so they can break even. Above that, they charge for risk.
GSA rate = risk-free rate + long-term default rate + risk charge.
The government can and does manage the risk charge down, by implicitly guaranteeing GSA bonds, and by allowing them to run on very low capital. They can manage it down further by allowing them to hold even less capital, or hinting more strongly that they’ll stand behind the GSAs in a crisis.
They can manage the charge for the long-term default rate down by saying that they’ll step in in a ‘crisis’ to subsidize the GSAs. Since most default costs over several economic cycles are incurred in the darkest depths of downturns, this effective reduction in the cost to the GSAs of the defaults could be dressed up as govt just doing what it should do – stepping in when all else fails.
I’m glad you are less cynical than me!
Patient renter in OC
-
AuthorPosts
- You must be logged in to reply to this topic.